9.8 Boundary solutions

Here, cases are considered which contain x = 0 or y = 0 as optimum. For more complex problems with boundary solutions for more than two variables, there is the so-called Kuhn-Tucker method, which, however, would go beyond the scope of this text. Explanations can be found in corresponding textbooks.
In the cases treated so far, we were always able to find points where the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) equaled the price ratio. However, if the MRS (i.e. the marginal utility ratio) is limited, i.e. there are values α and/or β to which applies,

α < MRS < β

it means that for price ratios px py which are smaller than α or larger than β there is no solution for the equation MRS = px py. There are no quantities of goods for which the slope of the budget line equals the slope of the isoquant.
If the MRS is greater than the price ratio px py,

MRS > px py

it means that x per additional unit brings more benefit than you lose by giving up as many units y as you need to save the money for one unit x. So by substituting x for y one could increase the benefit. This is possible until either the MRS has adapted to the price level by changing the goods ratios or until all y have been saved, i.e. until y = 0 angelangt ist. Since y cannot become negative, the solution in this case is to consume only x.
Usually, the isoquants in our models are convex, i.e. the marginal utility of a good decreases the more it is consumed. Thus, the MRS always changes in the direction of the price ratio due to substitution. However, if the price ratio is outside the value range of the MRS, i.e. px py < α or β < px py, then only a partial adjustment can take place, which ends when one of the two goods has been fully substituted.
If the MRS is smaller than the price ratio px py, the analogous consideration leads to the boundary point x = 0.
In the graph below, the MRS as the slope of the red tangent is directly comparable with the slope of the budget line. By increasing one of the prices, the price ratio can be adjusted in such a way that a boundary solution comes into play. Please note, a change of the budget, and thus a change of the achievable isoquant, alters the limits of the MRS and can thereby trigger a switch between boundary solution and normal solution.

The following example with c = 3 was used in the diagram.

U = x + c y + c

The MRS results in

GRS = d dxU x,y d dyU x,y = 2y + c y + c 2x + c x + c = y + c x + c

When equating with the price ratio and using the constraint, it results in:

d dxU x,y d dyU x,y = y + c x + c = px py ypy = px x + c cpy xpx + px x + c cpy = B x = B + c py px 2px y = B + c px py 2py

The functional equation of the isoquant is

U = x + c y + c y = U2 x + c c = B+cpypx 2px + c B+cpxpy 2py + c x + c c = B + c px + py 2 4pxpy c + x c

Boundary solution x = 0 and derivative at x = 0

ypy B = 0 y = B py GRSx=0 = y + c x + cx=0 = B py + c c = B cpy + 1

So if B cpy + 1 px py, then the boundary solution x = 0 applies. Boundary solution y = 0 and derivative at y = 0

xpx B = 0 x = B px GRSy=0 = y + c x + cx=0 = c B px + c

So if c B px+c px pypy px B cpx + 1, then the boundary solution y = 0 applies.


(c) by Christian Bauer
Prof. Dr. Christian Bauer
Chair of monetary economics
Trier University
D-54296 Trier
Tel.: +49 (0)651/201-2743
E-mail: Bauer@uni-trier.de
URL: https://www.cbauer.de