8.9 Income- and substitution- effects
The changes in consumption resulting from a change in the price of a good
can be divided into two effects: the substitution effect and the income
effect. The substitution effect results from the change in the price ratio,
the income effect from the induced change of the purchasing power of
the household. To illustrate this, we assume a price decline for Good 1
:
If the price of Good 1 falls, the consumer can afford more
of Good 1 for one unit of Good 2 than before. At the optimum point, this
exchange ratio (= market price ratio) corresponds to the marginal rate of
substitution, i.e. the ratio in which the goods can be exchanged without changing
the benefit. Now, if the price of Good 1 relative to Good 2 falls, the household
can save money without changing its benefit by shifting consumption
from Good 2 to Good 1 . This is due to the fact that the benefit-neutral
exchange ratio (marginal rate of substitution = slope of the tangent of the
benefit-indifference curve) is now greater than the price ratio (slope of the new
budget line). This shift in consumption towards Good 1 takes place until
the marginal rate of substitution corresponds to the price ratio (point
A).
In the graphic, the substitution effect is shown by the pink arrows. Point A lies on
the old indifference curve where the MRS equals the price ratio. The tangent, also
drawn in pink, shows that the slope corresponds to the slope of the new budget
line.
For Good 1 , the substitution effect is positive if the price of Good 1 . And it is
negative for Good 2 .
For the above analysis, we assume that none of the goods is a
SEC:Giffengueter
ist.
In point A, the household consumes only part of its disposable
income. It can achieve a higher indifference curve by exhausting its budget. To do
so, it consumes equally more of both goods until the new optimum is
reached.
The income effect is positive for both goods if the price of a good falls, and if none
of the goods is an inferior good. The brown arrows represent the income
effect.
The overall effect on Good 1 of a price reduction of Good 1 is
positive because both individual effects are positive. (If Good 1 were a Giffen
good, the income effect would be negative, since Giffen goods are always also
inferior goods). The overall effect on Good 2 of a price reduction of Good 1 can be
both positive and negative. This depends on the relative strength of the
substitution effect (negative) and income effect (positive). In the example above
we have used a Cobb-Douglas utility function. For these utility functions, the
total effect is always zero, since the income effect and the substitution effect
cancel each other out.
(c) by Christian Bauer
Prof. Dr. Christian Bauer
Chair of monetary economics
Trier University
D-54296 Trier
Tel.: +49 (0)651/201-2743
E-mail: Bauer@uni-trier.de
URL:
https://www.cbauer.de